Today's WSJ($) quotes self-appointed shareholder activist Nell Minow on the impact of the lawsuit against Walt Disney's directors over their handling of former Disney President Michael Ovitz's compensation package:
Because cases like this rarely go to trial, the Ovitz dispute "has every director quaking in his boots," says veteran shareholder activist Nell Minow, editor and chairman of the Corporate Library, a research group in Portland, Maine, that covers corporate governance.
Nonsense. This is a relatively unique case involving a rare confluence of several factors. First, you have a company with a long history of crony capitalism:
The case will animate, in great detail, the bad old days of Disney's corporate governance, when Mr. Eisner ruled a board that was widely seen as stacked with cronies too passive and unwilling to challenge him.
Second, you have an unusually large compensation package who structure created fewer incentives for Ovitz to work hard than it did for him to find a way of being terminated without cause. Finally, you had a board full of Eisner cronies and/or ceremonial directors who allowed the decisionmaking process to be usurped by Eisner and, indeed, allowed it to poractically disintegrate. If the directors are held liable for the breakdown in the decisionmaking process, that will hardly break much new legal ground. As I explain in the chapter on directors' duty of care in my Corporation Law and Economics treatise:
It is frequently said that the exercise of “reasonable diligence and care” is a precondition for the business judgment rule’s application. This phraseology is most unfortunate. It implies the necessity to inquire into the care exercised by the board .... The problem reduces to one of mere semantics, however, if we understand the requirement of “reasonable diligence and care” as being limited to the process by which the decision was made. Numerous Delaware decisions confirm that judicial references to a requirement of due care really go to the adequacy of the decisionmaking process—what the court has begun calling “process due care.” It would be better to follow the lead of those decisions and simply stop talking about whether the board exercised “reasonable diligence and care.” Instead, the requisite precondition [to application of the business judgment rule] would be better stated as a rational and good faith decisionmaking process. ...
[The leading case of Smith v.] Van Gorkom rests not on failure to comply with some judicially imposed decisionmaking model but on the absence of a sufficient record of any deliberative process. Put differently, if the decisionmaking process is adequate, the court will continue to defer to the decision that emerges from that process. The basic thrust of the opinion then is that the board must provide some credible, contemporary evidence that it knew what it was doing. If such evidence exists, the court will not impose liability—even if the decision proves to have been the wrong one.
By so focusing its opinion, the Van Gorkom court arguably created a set of incentives consistent with the teaching of the literature on group decisionmaking. The decision disfavors agenda control by senior management. The decision penalizes boards that simply go through the motions. The decision encourages inquiry, deliberation, care, and process. The decision strongly encourages boards to seek outside counsel and financial advice, which is consistent with evidence groupthink can be prevented by outside expert advice and evaluations. Even the court’s criticism of the board’s willingness to take action after a single meeting is consistent with suggestions that a “second-chance meeting” also helps prevent groupthink.
My discussion of this issue closes, however, with a warning that will become especially pertinent if Delaware Chancellor Chandler holds the Disney directors liable:
Van Gorkom probably has resulted in many board decisions being over-processed. In many cases, even relatively minor board decisions are subjected to exhaustive review, with detailed presentations by experts. Why? The answer lies in the incentive structures of the relevant players. Who pays the bill if the director is found liable for breaching the duty of care? The director. Who pays the bill for hiring lawyers and investment bankers to advise the board? The corporation and, ultimately, the shareholders. Suppose you were faced with potentially catastrophic losses, for which somebody offered to sell you an insurance policy. Better still, you don’t have to pay the premiums, someone else will do so. Buying the policy therefore doesn’t cost you anything. Would not you buy it?
It’s also important to consider the incentives of the lawyers who advise corporations. Deciding how much time and effort to spend on making decisions is itself a business decision. Because that decision is driven by liability concerns, however, legal advice is usually critical to the making of the decision. Why might lawyers have an incentive to encourage boards to over-invest in the decisionmaking process? The cynical answer is that a more complicated decisionmaking process, which is driven by liability concerns, is likely to result in higher fees. A less cynical explanation is that the law is full of sports, mutants, and mistakes. Clients often lack the information or willingness to recognize that their situation was one of the exceptions that proves the rule. Instead, clients tend to blame the lawyer for an adverse outcome even if the lawyer did nothing wrong. Because the lawyers will be blamed even if losing the case was an act of god equivalent to a 100-year flood, lawyers are often conservative in giving advice. (The term conservative here is not used in its political sense, but rather in the sense of being cautious.) In economic terms, lawyers are risk averse. In a risky situation, the best thing for the lawyer to do is to point the client towards strategies whose outcome is certain.
In sum, the incentives of both sellers and buyers of legal advice are congruent. Lawyers have strong incentives to encourage clients to expend a lot of time, energy, and money on the decisionmaking process, while corporate boards of directors have strong incentives to take that advice. All of which goes to show that otherwise puzzling things become readily explicable if one understands the economic incentives at play.